Ord 16-01ORDINANCE NO. 16-01
AN ORDINANCE OF THE CITY COMMISSION OF THE CITY OF
DELRAY BEACH, FLORIDA AMENDING CHAPTER 33, "POLICE
AND FIRE DEPARTMENTS", SUBHEADING 'PENSIONS", OF THE
CODE OF ORDINANCES OF THE CITY OF DELRAY BEACH,
FLORIDA BY AMENDING SECTION 33.66, "FINANCES AND FUND
MANAGEMENT," SECTION 33.66(E)(2)(b) TO PROVIDE FOR A
CHANGE IN THE INVESTMENT PARAMETERS FOR COMMON OR
CAPITAL STOCK; PROVIDING FOR REBALANCING; PROVIDING A
GENERAL REPEALER CLAUSE, A SAVING CLAUSE, AND AN
EFFECTIVE DATE.
WHEREAS, the City and the Board of Trustees of the Police and Fire Retirement Plan,
desire to change the parameters of investments in common or capital stock to enhance the performance of
the Retirement Fund while controlling the risk.
NOW, THEREFORE, be it ordained by the City Commission of the City of Delray
Beach, Florida as follows:
Section 1. That Section 33.66, "Finances and Fund Management", Section E(2)(b) be and
is hereby amended to read as follows:
(b) The Board of Trustees shall not invest more than five percent (5 %) of Trust
Fund its assets in the common or capital stock of any one issuing company, nor shall the aggregate
investment in common or capital stock in one company exceed five percent (5%) of the outstanding
common or capital stock of that company; nor shall the aggregate of the Fund's investments in
common or capital stock ~* ~"o* using the market value method exceed ~ seventy percent t~r~mx
(70%) of the Fund's assets, as measured on the last business day of each quarter. The Board of
Trustees shall rebalance the Fund's assets by the last business day of the following quarter.
Section 2.
same are hereby repealed.
That all ordinances or parts of ordinances in conflict herewith be and the
Section 3. That should any section or provision of this ordinance or any portion
thereof, any paragraph, sentence, or word be declared by a Court of competent jurisdiction to be invalid,
such decision shall not affect the validity of the remmnder hereof as a whole or part thereof other than the
part declared to be invalid.
Section 4.
reading.
That this ordinance shall become effective upon its passage on second and final
ED AND ADOPTED
2001.
in regular session on second and final reading on this the ~ff~day of
MAYOR
ATTEST:
City Clerk
First Reading
Second Reading.
MEMORANDUM
TO:
FROM:
SUBJECT:
DATE:
MAYOR AND CITY COMMISSIONERS
CITY MANAGER ~
AGENDA ITEM /0~ · - REGULAR MEETING OF MARCH 6,
2001
ORDINANCE NO. 16-01 (CHANGING INVESTMENT PARAMETERS IN
THE POLICE AND FIRE PENSION PLAN)
MARCH2,2001
This is second reading and public hearing for Ordinance No. 16-01 that would modify the Police and
Fire Pension Plan. The Police and Fire Pension Board has requested that the City Code be amended
to allow them to invest up to 70% of their assets in common stock. The Code currently limits this
type of investment to 60%. In the backup is a letter from Jeff Keating in which he recommends the
current limit of 60%, together with three artides on asset allocation strategies. After reading the
articles, I think we should approve increasing the limit on stocks to 70%. Based on almost 200 years
of historical stock market performance, this would give greater growth over the long tenn. However,
increasing the limit to 70% would increase the volatility of the asset value in the Police and Fire
Pension Fund. As a result, our exposure to year-to-year jumps in our required contribution would be
increased. But, our total contributions over the years should be less.
The Commission just needs to decide whether the long term decrease in our required contributions is
worth the increased exposure to wide swings in our required contribution.
At first reading on February 6m, the City Commission passed the ordinance by a unanimous vote.
Recommend approval of Ordinance No. 16-01 on second and final reading.
Ref'Agmemo14.Ord16-01Polic. e&Fire Pension Plan 2"~ Reading
[lTV OF DELRI:IV BEI:I[H
CITY ATTORNEY'S OFFICE
200 NW 1st AVENUE · DELRAY BEACH, FLORIDA 33444
TELEPHONE 561/243-7090 · FACSIMILE 561/278-4755
1993
DATE:
TO:
FROM:
SUBJECT:
Writer's Dtrect L~ne 561/243-7091
MEMORANDUM
January 25, 2001
City Commission
David Harden, City Manager
Susan A. Ruby, City Attorney
Ordinance Changing Investment Parameters in the Police and Fire Pension
Pension Plan
Enclosed is an ordinance that provides the Police and Fire Pension Plan Board of Trustees
may value its aggregate stock investments using the market value method instead of cost,
and provides that value of the stock may not exceed 70% (instead of 60%) of the funds
assets measured quarterly. It also provides for rebalancing of the Funds Assets.
Please place this ordinance on the February 6, 2001 City Commission agenda for first
re~~__~
SAR:ci
Enclosure
CC:
Alison Harty, City Clerk
Bill Adams, President, Police and Fire Pension Board
Steve Cypen, Esq.
James W. Lima, Esq.
ORDINANCE NO. ! 6- 01
AN ORDINANCE OF THE CITY COMMISSION OF THE
CITY OF DELRAY BEACH, FLORIDA AMENDING
CHAPTER 33, "POLICE AND FIRE DEPARTMENTS",
SUBHEADING 'PENSIONS", OF THE CODE OF
ORDINANCES OF THE CITY OF DELRAY BEACH,
FLORIDA BY AMENDING SECTION 33.66, "FINANCES
AND FUND MANAGEMENT," SECTION 33.66(E)(2)(b) TO
PROVIDE FOR A CHANGE IN THE INVESTMENT
PARAMETERS FOR COMMON OR CAPITAL STOCK;
PROVIDING FOR REBALANCING; PROVIDING A
GENERAL REPEALER CLAUSE, A SAVING CLAUSE, AND
AN EFFECTIVE DATE.
WHEREAS, the City and the Board of Trustees of the Police and Fire
Retirement Plan, desire to change the parameters of investments in common or capital stock to
enhance the performance of the Retirement Fund while controlling the risk.
NOW, THEREFORE, be it ordained by the City Commission of the City of
Delray Beach, Florida as follows:
Section 1. That Section 33.66, "Finances and Fund Management", Section
E(2)(b) be and is hereby amended to read as follows:
(b) The Board of Trustees shall not invest more than five percent (5 %)
of Trust Fund its assets in the common or capital stock of any one issuing company, nor
shall the aggregate investment in common or capital stock in one company exceed five
percent (5%) of the outstanding common or capital stock of that company; nor shall the
aggregate of the Fund's investments in common or capital stock at cost using the market
value method exceed sirdy seventy percent,,.,.~':c~ ~,~j~ (70 %) of the Fund's assets, as measured
on the last business day of each quarter. The Board of Trustees shall rebalance the Fund's
assets by the last business day of the following quarter.
Section 2. That all ordinances or parts of ordinances in conflict herewith be
and the same are hereby repealed.
Section 3. That should any section or provision of this ordinance or any
portion thereof, any paragraph, sentence, or word be declared by a Court of competent
jurisdiction to be invalid, such decision shall not affect the validity of the remainder hereof as a
whole or part thereof other than the part declared to be invalid.
Section 4.
second and final reading.
That this ordinance shall become effective upon its passage on
PASSED AND ADOPTED in regular session on second and final reading on this the
~ day of 2001.
MAYOR
ATTEST:
City Clerk
First Reading
Second Reading.
- 2 - Ord. No. 16-01
KF_ATING INVESTMENT COUNSELORS
REGISTERED INVESTMENT ADVISORS FOR INDIVIDUALS, RETIREMENT PLANS, TRUSTS AND FOUNDATIONS
Milene Walinski
City of Delray Beach
Finance Department
100 NW 1 st Avenue
Delray Beach, FL 33444
Dear Milene:
RECEIVED
CITY ~ANAGER
September 8, 2000
Enclosed are two articles on the issue of the optimum asset allocation between stocks
and bonds for Pension Plans or long term investors. Very simply, the optimum mix for a
Pension Plan is considered to be in the range of 60% in equities, with 40% in fixed income.
Historically, this balance has captured the vast majority of being invested 100% in equities
with 40% less risk as measured through price volatility. The major issue for the city is that
even though the police and fireman's pension plan has a long longevity, in essence, you are
always looking at 10 years or longer in terms of expected investment returns, the plan is
structured such that it impacts the city's finances on a year-to-year basis based on the
performance of the plan. Thus, the city should be looking at an asset allocation that is more
appropriate to an investor that has more of a short term orientation. The article by Jeremy
Siegel would suggest a more balanced 50%/50% structure between stocks and bonds.
Hopefully the enclosed articles will be of some assistance to you. If they don't, I
have a couple of other articles, but they are even more esoteric than these I have enclosed.
If you have any further questions, please feel free to call my office.
Truly yours,
J~ff-r~eating
JJK:lfs
Enclosures
777 EAST ATLANTIC AVENUE, SUITE 303 · DELRAY BEACH, FLORIDA 33483 · (561) 278-7862 · FAX (561) 265-1055
FOR
THE
JEREMY J.
SIEGEL
Second Edition
STOC KS FOR THE
LONG RUN
The Definitive
Guide to Financial
Market Returns
and Long-Term
Investment Strategies
JEREMY J. SIEGEL
Professor of Finance--
the Wharton School of the
University of Pennsylvania
McGraw-Hill
New York San Francisco Weshington, D.C. Auckland Bogot~
Caracas Lisbon London Madrid Mexico City Milan
Montreal New Delhi San Juan Singapore
Sydney Tokyo Toronto
Risk, Return and the Coming Age Wave
35
A second reason for the increase in correlation between stock
and bond returns is the strategy that portfolio managers follow to al-
locate assets. Most tactical allocation models, which money managers
use to minimize the risk and maximize the return of a portfolio, dic-
tate that the share of a portfolio that is allocated to stocks be a func-
tion of the expected return on stocks relative to that on bonds. As
interest rates rise, causing stock prices to fall, prospective bond re-
turns become more attractive, motivating these managers to sell
stocks. As a result, stock and bond prices move together. This is an ex-
ample of how the actions by portfolio managers trying to take advan-
tage of the historical correlation between stocks and bonds changes
their future correlation.
EFFICIENT FRONTIERS3
Modern portfolio theory describes how to alter the risk and return of a
portfolio by changing the mix between assets. Figure 2-6, based on the
nearly 200-year history of stock and bond returns, displays the risks and
returns that result from varying the proportion of stocks and bonds in a
portfolio.
The square at the bottom of each curve represents the risk and re-
turn of an all-bond portfolio, while the cross at the top of the curve rep-
resents the risk and return of an all-stock portfolio. The circle indicates
the minimum risk achievable by combining stocks and bonds. The
curve that connects these points represents the risk and return of all
blends of portfolios from 100 percent bonds to 100 percent stocks. This
curve, called the efficient frontier, is at the heart of modern portfolio
analysis and the foundation of asset allocation models.
Investors can achieve any combination of risk and return along the
curve by changing the proportion of stocks and bonds. Moving up the
curve means increasing the proportion in stocks and correspondingly
reducing the proportion in bonds. For short-term holding periods, mov-
ing up the curve increases both the return and the risk of the portfolio.
The slope of any point on the efficient frontier indicates the risk-return
trade-off for that allocation. By finding the points on the longer-term ef-
ficient frontiers that equal the slope on the one-year frontier, one can de-
termine the allocations that represent the same risk-return trade-offs for
all holding periods.
3 This section, which contains some advanced mater~al, can be skipped without loss of continuity.
of the"
for the
event.
36 PART l The Verdict of Histo~
FIGURE 2--6
Risk-Return Trade-Offs for Various HoLding Periods, 1802-1996
Fessor
Week
the co~
market
m;3st c(
case fO
necessi
ten--.a(
one of
historyl
Now
breakin
the toni
clusion!
power 1
safer f
more c(
with up(
tion thai
[] A tho
and c
have
sever(
[] How i
chant.
knowl
[] The a~
stock
investi
(:an el
[] How
investr
your n
[] Analy.
isons (
7%
3%.
2%.
h~b h " [o Min,mum Risk\ \ ~ b p 100% Bonds
I I I I ' I I " I I I
2% 4% 8% 8% 10% 12% 14% 16% 18% 20%
RECOMMENDED PORTFOLIO ALLOCATIONS
Table 2-2 indicates the percentage of an investor's portfolio that should
be invested in stocks based on both the risk tolerance and the holding
period of the investor.4 Four classes of investors are analyzed: the ultra-
conservative investor who demands maximum safety no matter the re-
turn, the conservative investor who accepts small risks to achieve extra
re.rum, the moderate risk-taking investor, and the aggressive investor
who is willing to accept substantial risks in search of extra returns.
The recommended equity allocation increases dramatically as the
holding period lengthens. The analysis indicates that, based on the histor-
4 The one-year proportions (except minimum risk point) are arbitrary, and are used as
benchmarks for other holding periods. Choosing different proportions as benchmarks does not
qualitatively change the following results.
CHAPTER 2 Risk, Return and the Commg Age Wave
37
TABLE 2-2
Portfoho Allocation: Percentage of Portfolio in Stocks Based on All Historical Data
Risk Hoidinc Period
·
Tolerance 1 year 5 years 10 years 30 years
Ultra-conservative
7,0% 25.0% 40.6% 71.3%
(Minimum Risk)
Conservative 25.0% 42.4% 61.3% 89.7%
Moderate 50.0% 62.7% 86.0% 112.9%
Risk-taking 75.0% 77.0% 104.3% 131.5%
ical returns on stocks and bonds, ultra-conservative investors should hold
nearly three-quarters of their portfolio in stocks over 30-year hoiding pe-
riods. This allocation is justified since stocks are safer than bonds in terms
of purchasing power over long periods of time. Conservative investors
should have nearly 90% of their portfolio in stocks, while moderate and
aggressive investors should have over 100 percent in equity. This alloca-
tion can be achieved by borrowing or leveraging an all-stock portfolio.
Given these striking results, it might seem puzzling why the holding
period has almost never been considered in portfolio theory. This is be-
cause modern portfolio theory was established when the academic pro-
fession believed in the random walk theory of security prices. As noted
earlier, under a random walk, the relative risk of securities does not
change for different time frames, so portfolio allocations do not depend
on the holding period. The holding period becomes a crucial issue in port-
folio theory when data reveal the mean reversion of the stock reL-urns.$
5 For a similar conclusion, see Nicholas Barbens, "Investing for the Long Run When Returns Are
Predictable," working paper, Umverslty of Chicago, July 1997 Paul Samuelson has shown that mean
reversion will increase equity holdings if investors have a risk aversion coefficaent greater than unity,
which most researehers find is the case. See Samuelson, "Long-Run Risk Tolerance When Equity
Return.', An., Mean Regr~_.~mg- Pseudoparadoxe~ and Vindication of 'Busmessmen's Pask'" in W C
Bramard, W D Nordhau.~, and I-I.W Watt.,,, ed~, Money, Macro¢commu~.~, and Pubhc Pohcy,
Cambridge, Mass. The MIT Press, 1991, pp. 181-200. See also Zvl Bodie, Robert Merton, and WLlliam
Samuelson, "Labor Supply Flexibdity and Portfolio Choice in a Lifecycle Model," Journal of Economic
Dynamtcs and Control, vol. 16, no 3 (July/October 1992), pp 427-450 Bod]e, et al. have shown that
equl~ holdings can vary w~th age because stock returns can be correlated with labor income.
~)
Seminar Proceedings
Investment Policy
April 18-20, 1994
Tokyo, Japan
Keith P. Ambachtsheer
Charles D. Ellis, CFA
John L. Maginn, CFA
David F. Swensen
John R. Thomas, CFA
Donald L. Tuttle, CFA, Moderator
Edited by Jan R. Squires, CFA
_.AIMR
Sponsored by the
Association for
Investment Management
and Research
and the
Security Analysts
Association of Japan
A Tale of Two Pension Funds:
Case Analysis (A)
{n making strategic asset allocation rec-
ommendations for their pension funds,
Jim Jones and Barbara Smith face a prob-
lem shared by every pension fund man-
ager: how to maximize the return on the
portfolio for an appropriate level of risk.
To find the solutions to this problem,
Jones and Smith must keep in mind the
pension fund balance sheet (Exhibit 1),
which will dictate to a significant degree
the risk-return trade-off for each fund.
Both investment managers believe
that their investment strategies should
be based on a going-concern view of
their pension plans. As going concerns,
the pension funds must prowde for the
impact of future wage and inflation ex-
periences on pension fund liabilities.
Jones and Smith agree that the immuniz-
ing investment strategy would combLne
some fixed-rate bonds with inflation-in-
dexed bonds and, possibly, a small eq-
uity position to hedge against unknown
future trends in wages. Deciding the
funds' appropriate long-term invest-
ment strategies, however, requires ad-
dressing two further issues.
F~rst, the U.S. Treasury is not yet
issuing inflation-indexed bonds. So,
what substitute asset(s) or alternative
strategies can be used for an inflation
hedge?
Second, how much incremental re-
turn should each fund seek relative to
the return produced by the immunizing
strategies? Any incremental return real-
ized will reduce the contributions re-
quired to finance the promised benefits
under the plans. Because Alpha Corpo-
ration Is a prwate-sector corporation
seeking to maximize shareholder wealth
and the Public Sector Retirement System
(PSRS) is sponsored by a state already
committed to funding a previous contri-
bution shortfall, both plans would wel-
come an investment policy that would
reduce their required contributions.
Thus, Jones and Smith face the difficult
task of improving the investment per-
formance of their pension funds m the
real world of uncertain future asset-class
returns and uncertain future economic
conditions shaping those returns.
Developing asset allocation recom-
mendations that will earn a return be-
yond the ideal immunizing strategy re-
quires a forecast of the expected returns
for different asset classes under different
economic conditions, and a determina-
tion of the asset allocation combination
that appears to offer the best return op-
portunities relative to the immunizing
strategy. Jones has started this process
by developing the forecasts of asset-
class returns for 1994 through 1998
given in Table 2 of the A case. To com-
plete the analysis, three questions must
be addressed:
· How realistic are Jones's esti-
mates of the returns for the 1994-
98 period?
· If the estimates are realistic, what
are the estimated returns for dif-
ferent portfolio compositions in
the three different economic sce-
narios for the 1994-98 period?
· What asset allocation strategies
should Jones and Smith recom-
mend to their boards of directors
or trustees?
The historical returns of different as-
set classes in different economic condi-
tions (Table 1 of the A case) can be used
to evaluate Jones's projected returns. To
use this historical information effec-
tively, Smith and Jones need to catego-
rize the different historical periods in
line with the definitions for the three
projected scenarios---degearmg, infla-
tion, or deflation. In terms of economic
growth and inflation, the 1952-65 period
corresponds most closely to the degear-
lng definition, the 1928--40 period to the
deflation definition, and the 1966-81 pe-
riod to the inflation definition.
Note, however, that the expected
GN
strt
wel
real
~Otl
5 25
of 1
and
the,
bdis
expt
verx
flati,
drev
Stoc,
rlSlrl
borlt.
mad
prol~
the F
set-c
int]a
h~st(
retu~
late
their
ally
stocJ
sign
nent per-
tds in the
sset-class
~onomic
n recom-
-~tum be-
ategy re-
:t returns
different
terrruna-
bination
.mm op-
~unizing
process
~f asset-
~ 1998
To corn-
ns must
~'s esti-
~e 1994-
tc, what
for dif-
:ions in
nic sce-
iod?
'ategies
recom-
rectors
:ent as-
condi-
.e used
-ns. To
effec-
atego-
~ds in
three
infla-
nomic
~eriod
-'gear-
to the
51 pe-
ected
economic conditions for 1994-98 do not
closely match any of the past periods in
Table 1. For example, in the 1952-65
period, the economy was characterized
by higher economic growth (3.3 percent
GNP growth) and lower inflation (1.4
percent) than is projected for the degear-
lng scenario. The degearing scenario as-
sumes that the U.S. economy will grow
slowly during the decade (2.5 percent
increase in annual GNP growth) as Fed-
eral Reserve tight-money policies hold
down the level of inflation (to 3.0 per-
cent annually) and the United States
works its way out of a debt overhang
and large federal government deficits.
Given its assumptions as to real
GNP growth and inflation and the 1994
structure of interest rates and dividend
yields, the degearing scenario projects
real returns for bills of 1.5 percent, for
bonds of 3.25 percent, and for stocks of
5.25 percent. The comparison 1952-65
period experienced real returns for bills
of 1.3 percent, for bonds of-0.2 percent,
and for stocks of 13.1 percent. Although
the actual and projected experiences for
bills are similar, the actual and projected
experiences for bonds and stocks are
very different. The difference lies in the
higher economic growth and lower in-
flation of the 1952--66 period, which
drew money into stocks and thus in-
creased stock multiples and improved
stock returns; at the same time, bond
yields were low in the early 1950s and
rising interest rates worked to depress
bond returns. After adjustments are
made for these differences, the returns
projected in Table 2 for the degearing
scenario appear realistic.
Similar differences exist between
the projected economic forecasts and as-
set-class returns for the deflation and the
inflation scenarios and their comparable
historical periods. Overall, Jones's real-
return projections for the period of the
late 1990s show bill returns, similar to
their historical experiences but gener-
ally better bond returns and poorer
stock returns relative to their historical
experiences.
Why would ]ones project experi-
ences for the future that appear to be
significantly different from the experi-
ences of the past? The answer to this
questions lies in his assumption that a
stock market correction will occur if, in-
stead of degearing, either a deflation or
inflation scenario occurs. Jones appar-
ently assumes that the deflation sce-
nario, particularly if started by a col-
lapse of the Japanese economy, would
result in substantially increased fears
about the future of the global economy,
a lowering of expectations for corporate
profits, and increased fears about the
outlook for stocks. This outcome would
generate an increase in the risk premium
on stocks, resulting in negative returns
on stocks in the 1994-98 period. In con-
trast, bond returns would be enhanced
as bond prices rose with a drop in long-
term interest rates accompanying the
switch to a deflation scenario. ]ones is
apparently suggesting that, in an infla-
tion scenario, higher capitalization-rate
requirements would, again, lower the
returns to stocks because of stock price
declines. Bond prices and returns
would suffer even more than stocks in
this scenario.
Disagreement with Jones's assump-
tions regarding the market reaction to
the deflation and inflation scenarios and
the subsequent impact on stocks would
lead to projected returns more attuned
to historical averages. His assumption
of a market correction appears reason-
able, however, in light of the long bull
market reflected in the returns to stocks
in the 1982-93 period and the market's
h~storically adverse reaction in short
periods to unexpected deflationary and
infla tionary environments as the market
seeks new equilibrium levels.
Assuming that the projected returns
in the different scenarios are reasonable,
Smith and Jones can calculate reason-
able returns for each of the four alterna-
tive portfolios in the three scenarios.
The portfolio returns are the weighted
averages of the projected asset-class re-
turns for each economic scenario. The
weightings would be the percentages
each asset class represents in the particu-
lar portfolio. The weighted real returns
of particular portfolios in the three eco-
nomic scenarios are given in Table A.
Cash was given no weighting in any of
75
T~)ie A. Weighted-Average Real Returns of ,~e.'~------d~d Portfolios by Economic
Scenario
Asset Mix De§earing Deflation Inflation
70°1o equity/30% debt 4.65% --4.35% -2 60%
60% equity/40% debt 4.45 -2.80 -2.80
S0o/o eqtuty/50% debt 4.25 -1.25 -3 00
40% equity/60% debt 4.05 0.30 -3.20
the portfolios suggested for analysis and
is not included in any of the portfolio
descriptions.
The different portfolios exhibit sig-
nificantly different return performance
in the three economic scenarios. In the
degearing scenario, an equity-heavy
portfolio performs slightly better than a
debt-heavy scenario, but in a deflatiofl
scenario, a debt-heavy portfolio per-
forms significantly better than an eq-
uity-heavy portfolio. Although none of
the portfolio mixes performs well in the
inflation scenario, an equity-heavy port-
folio does somewhat better than a debt-
heavy portfolio.
These return differences have sig-
nificant implications for the asset-mix
recommendations Jones and Smith
should make to their boards. If, as Smith
apparently believes, a good possibility
exists that the degearing scenario could
deteriorate into deflation, then the port-
folio should be debt heavy. This strategy
would not significantly reduce returns
in the degearing scenario but would
provide significant protection against
the downside of deflation. In the infla-
tion scenario, a shading toward equity
should produce the best (or least worst)
results. If the inflation scenario is a vi-
able possibility, the only hedge available
would be a sizable allocation of the port-
folio to cash equivalents (T-bills).
Based on the three possible scenar-
ios, which of the four portfolio alterna-
fives evaluated in Table A should be rec-
ommended for the Alpha Corporation
fund and the PSRS fund?
Alpha Corporation's current asset
mix of 70 percent equity/30 percent debt
reflects the company's ability and will-
ingness to assume larger risk than the
PSRS. If the asset-mix strategy does not
produce the desired real-return results,
Jones would have to inform the board of
directors that a larger future contribu-
tion to the corporation's pension plan is
required to provide its future defined
benefits. The result would be a reduc-
tion of corporate cash available for other
purposes for a time. In conclusion,
given the possible capital market envi-
ronments for 1994 through 1998, and
given Jones's view that inflation is more
likely than deflation, Alpha Corporation
is likely to maintain its 70 percent eq-
uity/30 percent debt strategy.
The PSRS's current asset mrx of 50
percent equity/50 percent debt reflects
its concerns about unfunded future li-
abilities and its resulting greater risk
aversion (relative to Alpha Corpora-
tion). If the PSRS's strategy does not
produce the desired real returns, the sys-
tem must request funds from the state
government, which involves raising
taxes or cutting expenditures, and from
the employees, which involves addi-
tional contributions from their salaries.
Neither necessity would be painless.
Therefore, given the possible 1994-98
environments and given Smith's view
that deflation is more likely than infla-
tion, the PSRS might find a 10-percent-
age-point shift from equity to debt desir-
able. The resulting mix, 40 percent eq-
uity/60 percent debt, would be rela-
tively conservative. In addition, be-
came of the inflation sensitivity of the
plan's liabilities, the PSRS should con-
sider shortening the duration of the debt
portfolio.
~set Allocation for Institutional
ios
San Frandsco, California
!February 10-11, 1986
D. Joehnk, CFA
P. Ambachtsheer
::'-Robert D. Amott
· Gary P. Brinson, CFA
· Kathleen A. Condon, CFA
"..; H. Gifford Fong
W'dliam L. Fouse, CFA
Walter R. Good, CFA
Sponsored by
The Institute of Chartered
Financial Analysts
Mark P. Kritzman, CFA
Greta E. Marshall, CFA
Robert H. Litzenberger
Douglas A. Love
Roger F. Murray
Claude N. Rosenberg, Jr.
William F. Sharpe
Strategic Approaches to Asset Allocation
Keith P. Ambachtsheer
When considering the subject of "strategic ap-
proaches to asset allocation," one should first
ask what is meant by strategy, tactics, and the
many other descriptors that are used in the area
of asset allocation. Why is asset allocation such
a foggy concept? Why are there such conceptual
difficulties in this area? It has a lot to do with
a confusion between means and ends. The defi-
nition I offer is: Asset allocation is the means
to achieve an appropriate package of risk, return,
and time through the three steps of context un-
derstanding, future thinking, and decision im-
plementation.
ASSET ALLOCATION: THE LONG-
TERM CONTRACT
There are two basic contexts in which to study
asset allocation, and they should be kept sepa-
rate. Context number one is long-term asset allo-
cation. To illustrate long-term asset allocation,
consider the case of the hypothetical Alpha
Corporation. They have made that conceptual
breakthrough, and they think of their defined
benefits plan as a financial business. As such,
they recognize that understanding and manag-
ing the plan balance sheet is the appropriate
way to proceed.
As seen in Figure 1, Alpha Corporation is
a billion dollar company with a fairly normal
looking principal business balance sheet. But
Alpha uses the extended balance sheet concept,
and as shown on the pension plan balance sheet,
the assets and liabilities are very significant rela-
tive to the main business assets and liabilities.
Assets in the pension plan are stated at the mar-
ket, and liabilities are stated on a "best-estimate
going-concern basis." In other words, they use
economic assumptions on a best-estimate basis
about return and inflation. The going-concern
part means that it is important to recognize,
for the final earnings plans at least, that the
liability is based on final earnings, not on the
level of earnings. Alpha Corporation has a signif-
icant asset cushion in the pension plan of $400
million, which in relation to the best estimate
of liabilities, amounts to a 44 percent asset cush-
ion.
When analyzing the pension plan balance
sheet, a number of policy issues need to be ad-
dressed. First is funding policy, or asset cushion
policy. Of concern here is the relationship be-
tween plan assets and projected plan liabilities
accrued to date. Should there be a large cushion
or a small cushion and why? The second issue
is asset mix policy, which deals with the left
side of the balance sheet. How are the assets
of the plan structured? Finally, there is a third
policy issue: investment management policy.
How will the asset mix policy be implemented?
Alpha's management realizes that there are
choices to be made. These can be seen in Figure
2, which shows the relationship between rates
of return of alternative asset allocation policies.
The company can have anything from a return
maximization policy to a risk minimization pol-
icy. With the return maximization policy, the
asset mix required to achieve a long-term 5 per-
cent (or even higher) real rate of return is, of
course, a 100 percent equity policy. At the other
extreme, the risk minimization policy is a policy
FIGURE !
Alpha Corporation (dollars in billions)
MAIN BUSINESS BALANCE SHEET
Assets Liabilities
Short term $1.2 Short term $0.6
Long term 1.2 Long term 0.8
$2 4 $1.4
Equity
Shareholders equity $1.0
PENSION PLAN BALANCE SHEET
Assets Liabilities
Short term $0 3 Short term
Long term 1.0 Long term
$1.3
Equity
Asset cushion
$0.3
0.6
$0.9
;ource' Kelth P. Ambachtsheer & Associates
24
FIGURE 2
Asset mix policy anc[ long-term return targets
Realistic 6
real return
targets
(percent) 5
With For With
return broad r~sk
maximizahon market minimization
focus portfolio focus
5ourc~. Keith P. Ambachtsheer & Assocmtes
of matching asset cash flows to liability cash
flows as closely as possible. The middle point
is to hold essentially the portfolio that the aggre-
gate of all investors hold, which should over
the long term achieve the same kind of real rate
of return as the real economy does in terms of
growth rate. That might be a 2.5 percent mid-
point.
The return projections are converted to im-
plicit long-term contribution rates in Table 1.
Earlier it was pointed out that pension costs
are independent of the return on plan assets.
We can see that on a best-estimate basis, a 5
percent long-term real rate of return is consistent
with a long-term corporate contribution rate of
6 percent of the payroll (that is, a money transfer
from the principal business). That figure in-
cludes updating pension costs for 60 percent
of the CPI inflation rate. A striking range in
funding costs can occur depending on which
TABLE 1. Long-term economic assumptions
and normal plan costs
Long-term
Long-term normal cost
Asset class real return (percent of payroll)
Stocks 5% 6%
Real estate 4 7
Long bonds 2
T-bills .5 14
Source' Ke~th P Ambachtsheer & Associates
asset mix is chosen, resulting in a potential long-
term contribution rate anywhere from 6 percent
to as high as 14 percent of payroll.
How does one choose? If this is the only
information, of course, the choice is obvious.
Go for the low contribution rate option. But this
decision is not that easy to make. The reason
is that sensible asset allocation decisions demand
a time context. For pension plans, the time frame
can be truly long term--probably in the neigh-
borhood of about 20 years. But one cannot ignore
concerns about shorter-term contribution rate
variability; for example, what might the contri-
bution rate have to be three to five years from
now? When you take a balance sheet perspec-
tive, the concern becomes the $400 million asset
cushion. Will it increase or decrease? Fluctua-
tions in this asset cushion could be quite signifi-
cant over a three- to five-year period.
So the fundamental issue in long-term asset
allocation is the question of trading off long-term
good news against the possibility of shorter-term
bad news. You can look at this dilemma in a
contribution rate context, where lower long-term
contributions must be balanced against greater
shorter-term contribution uncertainty. Alterna-
tively, you can look at it in a balance sheet context
and seek higher long-term asset cushion growth
against shorter-term cushion size uncertainty.
The good news is that the long-term contribution
rate, including updating pensions in pay for in-
flation, implies a 6 percent contribution rate.
FIGURE 3
The future contribution rate trade-off range
The R~turn Maximizing Policy The Risk Minimizing Policy
Good news Bad news
No good or bad news
Long-term
contributions
are
6%
of payroll
Shorter-term
contributions
could be over
15%
of payroll
in deflation
Source. Ke~th P. Ambachtsheer & Asso~ates.
Contribuhons
will not vary
far from
10%
of 12ayroli
in short term
or long term
The bad news is that if you end up with an
extended period, perhaps three to five years,
when equities do very poorly, your contribution
rate could go up to 15 percent three to five years
later.
In the risk minimizing policy, there is no
good news or bad news by definition. Contribu-
tions will not vary far from 10 percent of payroll
in the short or long term (see Figure 3). Many
corporate managers, when they are shown these
alternatives, prefer to look at the trade-off in
the balance sheet context. The good news with
the return maximizing policy is that continued
cushion growth means eventual lower corp6rate
contributions or higher benefits in the long term.
The bad news is that the cushion can disappear
in the shorter term. With the risk minimizing
policy, there is again no particularly good news
or bad news; cushion size is highly predictable
(see Figure 4).
THE ROLE OF FUTURE THINKING
IN ASSET ALLOCATION
Given the framework in which to make asset
allocation decisions, the next element in the deci-
sion process is dealing with an uncertain future.
In this context, dealing explicitly with uncer-
tainty is crucial. Over time, we have developed
two approaches to dealing with that future. The
first method, the Monte Carlo simulation, as-
sesses the future through a series of probability
distributions for stock returns, bond returns,
cash returns, and inflation returns and how they
are expected to be correlated. From those expec-
tations, a computer can develop hundreds or
FIGURE 4
The future asset cushion trade-off range
The Return Maximizing Policy The Risk Mimmizmg Policy
Good news Bad news
No good or bad news
Continued
cushion
growth
means lower
costs 0~'
higher
benafits
in long term
Cushion
disappears
in
deflation
Source: Ke~th P. Ambachtsheer & Associates.
Cushion
size
highly
predictable
26
thousands of possible outcomes by drawing out
these distributions. The output, as illustrated
in Figure 5, shows contributions as a percent
of payroll on the left scale and different weight-
ings of equities as opposed to bonds across the
bottom. When moving from low risk to higher
risk, the percent of equities in the portfolio and
the potential contribution rate increases and the
50th percentile contribution rate decreases.
The other technique, called the scenario ap-
proach, is a little more hands-on and allows you
to put a little more color into the analysis. The
four possible scenarios are summarized in Table
2. To relate the scenario approach to dealing
with an uncertain future, again consider Alpha
Corporation. The implications for the Alpha
pension plan contribution rate depend on the
firm's asset allocation policy. For example, in
the deflation case, with the return maximizing
policy, the results are very unpleasant with the
projected contribution rate going way up (see
Figure 6). Figure 7 presents the same results
in a plan balance sheet (asset cushion) context.
DECISIONS AND
THEIR IMPLEMENTATION
After determining the context and allowing for
an uncertain future, the decision and implemen-
tation steps follow. In the case of Alpha Corpora-
tion, management decided that, as much as pos-
sible, they wanted to maximize long-term real
FIGURE 5
Distributions of contributions as a percent of payroll for various bond/stock asset mixes
Contributlonslpayroll
(percent) (inverted scale)
9-
10
6.3 !
?.0
7.7
8.2
8.7
6.1
6.8
7.6
8.1
8.6
5.3
6.6
7.3
8,1
8.7
5.1
6.4
7.3
8.1
8.7
4.5
6.0
7.2
8.2
8.8
4.1
5.6
7.1
8.3
9.1
I I I I I I
A B C D E F
0% 20% 40% 50% 70% 90%
Percentile
90th
75th
50th
25th
10th
Percent in equities
Source: Bankers Trust Company.
27
TABLE 2. Possible three- to five-year capital market environ.men~s
Good ~imes: Steady output and produc~vity growth, low
inflation rate, positive expectations about the future.
Stagflation: Uneven output and productivity growth, infla-
~on rate in the 6-9 percent range, confused expectations
about the future.
Rising inflation: Uneven output and productivity growth,
debt monetization, inflation rate nsmg above 10 percent,
dynamics expected to continue
Deflation: Output stagnant to falling, inflation Iow and fail-
ing, future looks bleak.
The capital markets
Stocks do very well, followed by real estate and long bonds.
Short-term investments left far behind.
No predictable differences in asset class r. eturns.
Real estate and other tangibles do best, stocks and short-
term investments mediocre, long bonds worse by far.
High-quality tong bonds best by far, cash mediocre, real
estate poor, stocks worst.
Source. Kelth P. Ambachtsheer & Assooates.
return, subject to "being whole" (that is, having
a positive asset cushion in the worst case out-
come) on a three- to five-year basis. Using this
particular set of numbers, being whole is
achieved through a significant real estate posi-
tion, which is the hedge against the rising infla-
t'ion outcome, and a significant long-bond posi-
tion, which is the hedge against the deflation
outcome. The purpose for those two positions
is risk control. The "basic" asset mix in ~
8 results.
-- A lot of interesting things can be done with
the basic asset mix policy to improve its risk-
reward characteristics. See the expanded asset
mix policy in Figure 8. One aspect of the ex-
panded asset mix policy is the shift account.
That account can be in domestic stocks, long
bonds, or T-bills. It is funded from the basic
policy by taking 10 percentage points of the long-
bond position and 10 percentage points of the
stock position and putting them into a shift ac-
count. This is a good way to shift the focus
from an asset allocation approach that concen-
trates on risk control to one that concentrates
FIGURE 6
Sixth-year contribution rate projections
Return
maxim~zahon
w~th "bad news"
Percent -15 -
-10
-5
0
5
10 --
15
20 -
Source' Ke~ih P Ambachtsheer & Assooates.
Good times
Deflation
Return Risk
maximization mlnlm~zahon
no "bad news"
Good times
Deflation
Deflation I [ Rising
inflation
28
FIGURE 7
Five-year asset cushion swing projections
Return Return Risk
maximization maximization m,mm~zataon
with "bad news" no "bad news"
Good times
Deflahon
$ billions 1.6 ~
1.2
0,8
0,4
-0.4
-0.8
Source- Ke~th P. Ambachtsheer & Assooates.
Good hmes
Deflation
Deflation
Risang
inflation
on value added. When moving to a shod-term
asset allocation focus, however, the investment
context changes very significantly.
RISK CONTROL AND
RETURN ENHANCEMENT
Short-term asset allocation is a process that fo-
c-~-,~.s not on risk control but on return enhance-
-~ent. The objective is to add return to an other-
wise passive situation. In the short-term asset
allocation context, we have to raise the question
as to whether there are correlations between
yesterday, today, and tomorrow. In other
words, are there relationships between past and
present observable events and future stock
prices and interest rates? How you answer that
question is absolutely crucial to whether you
should engage in short-term active asset alloca-
tion. If you believe there are no such linkages,
stop now. If you believe there are linkages that
can be identified, then there is a place for active
asset allocation.
Table 3 shows the five bases that have to
be touched to be effective, to maximize the
chances of success. Step 1: What do you believe
about the relationships between events yester-
day and today and stock prices and interest rates
tomorrow? In other words, what is your theory
of capital assets pricing? You must consider that
issue and think about your belief of how inflation
expectations will affect bond prices, the impact
of real GNP growth on stock prices, and so forth.
This leads to Step 2: Identify the predictors that
are important to security valuation. In effect,
what can I observe today that will affect the
valuation factors tomorrow? And you might say,
for example, "Well, I think monetary policy to-
day might affect inflation expectations tomor-
row,'' thereby identifying that particular pre-
dictor.
Step 3: What is the relationship between the
predictors and the variables that you are trying
to forecast (future stock prices and interest
rates)? In Step 3, you are actually th~nking, for
example, about how sensitive changes in mone-
tary policy are today to changes in inflation ex-
pectations tomorrow--which, in turn, will im-
pact stock and bond prices tomorrow. Step 4:
Establish your decision rules. You can't just stop
with the output of the process in terms of expec-
tations about the future; you have to act on them
and you have to act on them in an intelligent
way. Decision rules used by money managers
are often quite naive. For example, managers
often do not consider that they might not be
perfect at making capital markets forecasts. Your
actual decision rules depend very much on how
good you thir~k your forecasts are and on the
transaction costs. These are the real world issues
,{
29
As the Commission is aware, the Police and Fire Pension Board has requested that the
City Code be amended to allow them to invest up to 70% of their assets in common
stock. The Code currently limits this type of investment to 60%. In the backup is a letter
from Jeff Keating in which he recommends the current limit of 60%, together with three
articles on asset allocation strategies. After reading these articles, I think we should
approve increasing the limit on stocks to 70%. Based on almost 200 years of historical
stock market performance, this would give greater growth over the long term. However,
increasing the limit to 70% would increase the volatility of the asset value in the Police
and Fire Pension Fund. As a result, our exposure to year-to-year jumps in our required
contribution would be increased. But, our total contributions over the years should be
less. The Commission just needs to decide whether the long term decrease in our
required contributions is worth the increased exposure to wide swings in our required
contribution.
MEMORANDUM
TO:
FROM:
SUBJECT:
DATE:
MAYOR AND CITY COMMISSIONERS
CITY MANAGER ~
AGENDA ITEM /~0.~.. REGULAR MEETING OF FEBRUARY 6, 2001
ORDINANCE NO. 16-01 (CHANGING INVESTMENT PARAMETERS IN
THE POLICE AND FIRE PENSION PLAN)
FEBRUARY 2, 2001
As the Commission is aware, the Police and Fire Pension Board has requested that the City Code be
amended to allow them to revest up to 70% of their assets in common stock. The Code currently
limits this type of investment to 60%. In the backup is a letter from Jeff Keating in which he
recommends the current limit of 60%, together w~th three articles on asset allocation strategies. After
reading these articles, I think we should approve increasing the lin-ut on stocks to 70%. Based on
almost 200 years of historical stock market performance, this would give greater growth over the long
term. However, increasing the lirmt to 70% would increase the volatility of the asset value in the
Police and F~re Pension Fund. As a result, our exposure to year-to-year jumps in our required
contribution would be increased. But, our total contributions over the years should be less.
The Commission just needs to decide whether the long term decrease in our required contributions is
worth the increased exposure to wide swings m our required contribution.
ReiSAgmemol4.Ord.16-01.Police & Fire Pension Plan
DATE:
TO:
FROM:
SUBJECT:
Writer's D~rect Line 561/243-7091
MEMORANDUM
January 25, 2001
City Commission
David Harden, City Manager
Susan A. Ruby, City Attorney
Ordinance Changing Investment Parameters in the Police and Fire Pension
Pension Plan
Enclosed is an ordinance that provides the Police and Fire Pension Plan Board of Trustees
may value its aggregate stock investments using the market value method instead of cost,
and provides that value of the stock may not exceed 70% (instead of 60%) of the funds
assets measured quarterly. It also provides for rebalancing of the Funds Assets.
Please place this ordinance on the February 6, 2001 City Commission agenda for first
re~
SAR:ci
Enclosure
CC:
Alison Harty, City Clerk
Bill Adams, President, Police and Fire Pension Board
Steve Cypen, Esq.
James W. Linn, Esq.
ORDINANCE NO. 16- 01
AN ORDINANCE OF THE CITY COMMISSION OF THE
CITY OF DELRAY BEACH, FLORIDA AMENDING
CHAPTER 33, "POLICE AND FIRE DEPARTMENTS",
SUBHEADING 'PENSIONS", OF THE CODE OF
ORDINANCES OF THE CITY OF DELRAY BEACH,
FLORIDA BY AMENDING SECTION 33.66, "FINANCES
AND FUND MANAGEMENT," SECTION 33.66(E)(2)(b) TO
PROVIDE FOR A CHANGE IN THE INVESTMENT
PARAMETERS FOR COMMON OR CAPITAL STOCK;
PROVIDING FOR REBALANCING; PROVIDING A
GENERAL REPEALER CLAUSE, A SAVING CLAUSE, AND
AN EFFECTIVE DATE.
WHEREAS, the City and the Board of Trustees of the Police and Fire
Retirement Plan, desire to change the parameters of investments in common or capital stock to
enhance the performance of the Retirement Fund while controlling the risk.
NOW, THEREFORE, be it ordained by the City Commission of the City of
Delray Beach, Florida as follows:
Section 1. That Section 33.66, "Finances and Fund Management", Section
E(2)(b) be and is hereby amended to read as follows:
(b) The Board of Trustees shall not invest more than five percent (5 %)
of Trust Fund i-ts assets in the common or capital stock of any one issuing company, nor
shall the aggregate investment in common or capital stock in one company exceed five
percent (5%) of the outstanding common or capital stock of that company; nor shall the
aggregate of the Fund's investments in common or capital stock at cost using the market
value method exceed s-bag seventy percentw,-t~n e,~jx (70%) of the Fund's assets, as measured
on the last business day of each quarter. The Board of Trustees shall rebalance the Fund's
assets by the last business day of the following quarter.
Section 2. That all ordinances or parts of ordinances in conflict herewith be
and the same are hereby repealed.
Section 3. That should any section or provision of this ordinance or any
portion thereof, any paragraph, sentence, or word be declared by a Court of competent
jurisdiction to be invalid, such decision shall not affect the validity of the remainder hereof as a
whole or part thereof other than the part declared to be invalid.
Section 4.
second and final reading.
That this ordinance shall become effective upon its passage on
PASSED AND ADOPTED in regular session on second and final reading on this the
~ day of 2001.
MAYOR
ATTEST:
City Clerk
First Reading
Second Reading
- 2 - Ord. No. 16-01
TING
INWESTMENT
COLTNSELORS INC.
REGISTERED INVESTMENT ADVISORS FOR INDIVIDUALS, RETIREMENT PLANS, TRUSTS AND FOUNDATIONS
September 8, 2000
Milene Walinski
City of Delray Beach
Finance Department
100 NW 1 st Avenue
Delray Beach, FL 33444
Dear Milene:
Enclosed are two articles on the issue of the optimum asset allocation between stocks
and bonds for Pension Plans or long term investors. Very simply, the optimum mix for a
Pension Plan is considered to be in the range of 60% in equities, with 40% in fixed income.
Historically, this balance has captured the vast majority of being invested 100% in equities
with 40% less risk as measured through price volatility. The major issue for the city is that
even though the police and fireman's pension plan has a long longevity, in essence, you are
always looking at 10 years or longer in terms of expected investment returns, the plan is
structured such that it impacts the city's finances on a year-to-year basis based on the
performance of the plan. Thus, the city should be looking at an asset allocation that is more
appropriate to an investor that has more of a short term orientation. The article by Jeremy
Siegel would suggest a more balanced 50%/50% structure between stocks and bonds.
Hopefully the enclosed articles will be of some assistance to you. If they don't, I
have a couple of other articles, but they are even more esoteric than these I have enclosed.
If you have any further questions, please feel free to call nay office.
Truly yours,
'~ f~!~--',Ke at[ng
President;
JJK:lfs
Enclosures
777 EAST AI'LANTIC AVENUE, SUI[E303 · DELRAYBEACH, FLORIDA 33483 · (561)278-7862 · FAX (561)265-1055
FOR
THE
3EREMY J. SI
EL
Second Edition
STOCKS FOR THE
LONG RUN
The Definitive
Guide to Financial
Market Returns
and Long-Term
Investment Strategies
JEREMY J. SIEGEL
Professor of Finance--
the Wharton School of the
Un iversity of Pen nsylva nia
('~' I' /
McGraw-Hill
New York San Francisco Washington, D.C. Auckland Bogot~
Caracas Lisbon London Madrid Mexico Clty Milan
Montreal New Delhi San Juan Singapore
Sydney Tokyo Toronto
2 R~sk, Return and the Coming Age Wave
35
A second reason for the increase in correlation between stock
and bond returns is the strategy that portfolio managers follow to al-
locate assets. Most tactical allocation models, which money managers
use to minimize the risk and maximize the return of a portfolio, dic-
tate that the share of a portfolio that is allocated to stocks be a func-
tion of the expected return on stocks relative to that on bonds. As
interest rates rise, causing stock prices to fall, prospective bond re-
turns become more attractive, motivating these managers to sell
stocks. As a result, stock and bond prices move together. This is an ex-
ample of how the actions by portfolio managers trying to take advan-
tage of the historical correlation between stocks and bonds changes
their future correlation.
EFFICIENT FRONTIERS:~
Modern portfolio theory describes how to alter the risk and return of a
portfolio by changing the mix between assets. Figure 2-6, based on the
nearly 200-year history of stock and bond returns, displays the risks and
returns that result from varying the proportion of stocks and bonds in a
portfolio.
The square at the bottom of each curve represents the risk and re-
turn of an all-bond portfolio, while the cross at the top of the curve rep-
resents the risk and return of an all-stock portfolio. The circle indicates
the minimum risk achievable by combining stocks and bonds. The
curve that connects these points represents the risk and return of all
blends of portfolios from 100 percent bonds to 100 percent stocks. This
curve, called the efficient frontier, is at the heart of modem portfolio
analysis and the foundation of asset allocation models.
Investors can achieve any combination of risk and return along the
curve by changing the proportion of stocks and bonds. Moving up the
curve means increasing the proportion in stocks and correspondingly
reducing the proportion in bonds. For short-term holding periods, mov-
ing up the curve increases both the return and the risk of the portfolio.
The slope of any point on the efficient frontier indicates the risk-return
trade-off for that allocation. By finding the pomts on the longer-term ef-
ficient frontiers that equal the slope on the one-year frontier, one can de-
termine the allocations that represent the same risk-return trade-offs for
all holding periods.
3 Th~s section, which contains some advanced material, can be skipped w~thout loss of connnu~ty
of the
for the
event.
36 PART 1 The Verdzm of HlstoD,
FIGURE 2-6
Risk-Return Trade-Offs for Various Holding Periods, 1802-1996
fessor .
Week
the cos
market
mbst cc
case fa
necessi
ten--am
one Of:
historyl
Now
breakin
the Lan1
clusion;
power
safer !
more
with
tJon thai
· A tho
and c
~ove
seven
· How t
chanc.
knowl
a'w'n
· The a~
stock ~
investi
con el'
· How
invesfr
your n
· Analy.
Jsorl$
8%
6%
2%.
1%'
30 yr
~a h " Jo Mlmmum Risk
o% 2% 4% 6%
I .... I I " i
10% 12% 14% 18% 18% 20%
RECOMMENDED PORTFOLIO ALLOCATIONS
Table 2-2 indicates the percentage of an investor's portfolio that should
be invested in stocks based on both the risk tolerance and the holding
period of the investor.4 Four classes of investors are analyzed: the ultra-
conservative investor who demands maximum safety no matter the re-
turn, the conservative investor who accepts small risks to achieve extra
remrv,, the moderate risk-taking investor, and the aggressive investor
who is willing to accept substantial risks in search of extra returns.
The recommended equity allocation increases dramatically as the
holding period lengthens. The analysis indicates that, based on the histor-
4 The one-year proportions (except rrammum risk point) are arbitrary, and are used as
bench.marks for other holding periods. Choosing different proportions as benchmarks does not
quahtahvely change the following results.
CHAPTER 2 Risk, Return and the Comln~ Age Wave
37
TABLE 2-2
Portfoho Allocation. Percentage of Portfoho ~n Stocks Based on All H~storical Data
Risk Holdin¢ Period
·
Tolerance I year 5 years 10 years 30 years
Ultra-conservative
7.0% 25 0% 40.6% 71.3%
(Minimum Risk)
Conservative 25 0% 42.4% 61.3% 89.7%
Moderate 50,0% 62,7% 86,0% 112.9%
Risk-taking 75.0% 77,0% 104.3% 131.5%
ical ret'urns on stocks and bonds, ultra-conservative investors should hold
nearly three-quarters of their portfolio in stocks over 30-year hoiding pe-
riods. This allocation is justified since stocks are safer than bonds in terms
of purchasing power over long per]ods of time. Conservative investors
should have nearly 90% of their portfoho in stocks, while moderate and
aggressive investors should have over 100 percent in equity. This alloca-
tion can be achieved by' borrowing or leveraging an all-stock portfolio.
Given these sinking results, it might seem puzzling why the holding
period has almost never been considered in portfolio theory. This is be-
cause modern portfolio theory was established when the academic pro-
fession beheved tn the random walk theory of secun ,t-y prices. As noted
earlier, under a random walk, the relative risk of securities does not
change for different time frames, so portfolio allocations do not depend
on the holding period. The holding period becomes a crucial issue in port-
folio theory when data reveal the mean reversion of the stock returns.$
5 For a similar conclusion, see Nicholas Barber]s, "Investing for the Long Run When Returns Are
Predictable," working paper, University of Chicago, July 1997 Paul Samuelson has shown that mean
reversion wdl increase equity holdings if investors have a r]sk aversion coefficient greater than unity,,
which mo~t researchers fred is the case See Samuelson, "Long-Run Risk Tolerance When Eqmty
Return.', Arc Mean Regr~_.'~mg Pseudoparadoxe~ and Vmdicatmn of 'Busincssmen's Ribk'" ~n WC
Bramard, W D Nordhau.., and } l W Watt.., ed~, Money, ,klacroct,mmm~, and Pubhc Pohcy,
Cambridge, Mass The MIT Press. 1991. pp 181-200 See also Zvi Bodie. Robert Merton. and William
Samuelson, "Labor Supply Flexibility. and Portfolio Choice tn a Lifecycle Model." Journal of Economic
Dynamtcsat~d C(mtrol, vol 16, no 3 (July/October 1992). pp 427-450 Bodie, et al have shown that
eqmty ho[drags can vary. v.,~th age because stock returns can be correlated with labor income
Seminar Proceedings
Investment Policy
April 18--20, 1994
Tokyo, Japan
Keith P. Ambachtsheer
Charles D. Ellis, CFA
John L. Maginn, CFA
David F. Swensen
John R. Thomas, CFA
Donald L. Tuttle, CFA, Moderator
Edited by Jan R Squires, CFA
..~IMR
Sponsored by the
Association for
Investment Management
and Research
and the
Security Analysts
Association of Japan
A Tale of Two Pension Funds:
Case Analysis (A)
In making strategic asset allocation rec-
ommendations for their pension funds,
Jim Jones and Barbara Smith face a prob-
lem shared by every pension fund man-
ager: how to maximize the return on the
portfolio for an appropriate level of risk.
To find the solutions to this problem,
Jones and Smith must keep in mind the
pension fund balance sheet (Exhibit 1),
which will dictate to a significant degree
the risk-return trade-off for each fund.
Both investment managers believe
that their investment strategies should
be based on a going-concern view of
their pension plans As going concerns,
the pension funds must provide for the
impact of future wage and inflation ex-
periences on pension fund liabilities.
Jones and Smith agree that the ~mmumz-
mg unvestment strategy would combine
some fixed-rate bonds with inflation-in-
dexed bonds and, possibly, a small eq-
mty position to hedge against unknown
future trends un wages. Deciding the
funds' appropriate long-term invest-
ment strategies, however, requires ad-
dressing t~vo further issues
First, the U S. Treasury ~s not yet
issuing inflation-indexed bonds. So,
what subsntute asset(s) or alternative
strategies can be used for an mflatlon
hedge~
Second, how much incremental re-
turn should each fund seek relative to
the return produced by the lmmumzmg
strategies? Any incremental return real-
ized wdl reduce the contributions re-
quired to finance the prom~sed benefits
under the plans Because Alpha Corpo-
ration Is a private-sector corporation
seekung to maximize shareholder wealth
and the Public Sector Retirement System
(PSRS) is sponsored by a state already
committed to funding a previous contn-
buhon shortfall, both plans would wel-
come an investment policy that would
reduce their required contributions.
Thus, Jones and Smith face the difficult
task of improving the investment per-
formance of their pension funds in the
real world of uncertain future asset-class
returns and uncertain future economic
conditions shaping those returns.
Developing asset allocation recom-
mendations that will earn a return be-
yond the ideal immunizing strategy re-
quires a forecast of the expected returns
for different asset classes under different
economic conditions, and a determina-
tion of the asset allocation combination
that appears to offer the best return op-
portunities relative to the immunizing
strategy. Jones has started this process
by developing the forecasts of asset-
class returns for 1994 through 1998
given in Table 2 of the A case. To com-
plete the analysis, three questions must
be addressed.
· How reahst]c are Jones's esti-
mates of the returns tot the 1994-
98 period?
· If the estunates are reahshc, what
are the estimated returns for dif-
ferent portfolio compositions in
the three different economic sce-
narios for the 1994-98 period?
· What asset allocation strategies
should Jones and Smith recom-
mend to their boards of directors
or trustees?
The historical returns of different as-
set classes m different economic condi-
tions (Table 1 of the A case) can be used
to evaluate Jones's prelected returns. To
use th~s historical information effec-
tively, Smith and Jones need to catego-
rize the different historical periods in
line with the definmons for the three
prelected scenarios--degearmg, infla-
tion, or deflation. In terms of economic
growth and inflation, the 1952--65 period
corresponds most closely to the degear-
lng definition, the 1928--t0 period to the
deflation definition, and the 1966-81 pe-
riod to the inflation defimtion.
Note, however, that the expected
74
GN
s/ri:
rea i
ben
52:
pur~
et l
and
the
bdl'~
e'.,p~
vet,.
h~g~
tlat~
dre~
orca
stoc
rlsir'
ben,
c, Ct?p
the
set-t
h~stt
retu
late
the~
stoc
enc~
sigr
nent per-
tds in the
sset-class
~onoraic
CIS.
n recom-
.'turn be-
ategy re-
J returns
different
termuna-
btnation
turn op-
~unizing
process
~f asset-
gh 1998
To corn-
ns must
¥s esti-
1994--
lC, what
for dif-
'ions in
13.1C sce-
iod~
ategies
recom-
rectors
-ent as-
condi-
e used
-ns To
effec-
atego-
ods tn
three
infla-
nomic
~enod
-'gea r-
to the
51 pe-
ected
economic conditaons for 1994-98 do not
closely match any of the past periods in
Table 1. For example, in the 1952--65
period, the economy was characterized
by higher economic growth (3.3 percent
GNP growth) and lower irfflation (1.4
percent) than is projected for the degear-
ing scenario. The degearing scenario as-
sumes that the U.S. economy will grow
slowly during the decade (2.5 percent
increase in annual GNrp growth) as Fed-
eral Reserve tight-money policies hold
down the level of inflation (to 3.0 per-
cent annually) and the United States
works its way out of a debt overhang
and large federal government deficits.
Given its assumptions as to real
GNP growth and inflation and the 1994
structure of interest rates and dividend
yields, the degearing scenario projects
real returns for bills of 1 5 percent, for
bonds of 3 25 percent, and for stocks of
5.25 percent. The comparison 1952-65
period experienced real returns for bills
of 1.3 percent, for bonds of-0.2 percent,
and for stocks of 13.1 percent. Although
the actual and projected experiences for
btlls are similar, the actual and projected
experiences for bonds and stocks are
very different. The difference lies in the
higher economic growth and lower in-
flat,on of the 1952--66 period, which
drew money tnto stocks and thus in-
creased stock multiples and improved
stock returns; at the same time, bond
y~etds were low in the early 1950s and
rising interest rates worked to depress
bond returns. After adjustments are
made for these differences, the returns
projected in Table 2 for the degearing
scenario appear realistic.
Similar differences exist between
the projected economic forecasts and as-
set-class returns for the deflation and the
tnt'la tlon scenarios and their comparable
historical periods. Overall, Jones's real-
return projections for the period of the
late 1990s show bill returns, similar to
thmr historical experiences but gener-
ally better bond returns and poorer
stock returns relative to their historical
experiences.
Why would Jones project experi-
ences for the future that appear to be
significantly different from the experi-
ences of the past? The answer to this
questions lies in his assumption that a
stock market correction will occur if, in-
stead of degearing, either a deflation or
inflation scenario occurs. Jones appar-
ently assumes that the deflation sce-
nario, particularly if started by a col-
lapse of the Japanese economy; would
result in substantially increased fears
about the future of the global economy,
a lowering of expectations for corporate
profits, and increased fears about the
outlook for stocks. This outcome would
generate an increase in the risk premium
on stocks, resulting in negative returns
on stocks in the 1994-98 period. In con-
trast, bond returns would be erdaanced
as bond prices rose with a drop in long-
term interest rates accompanying the
switch to a deflation scenario. Jones is
apparently suggesting that, in an infla-
tion scenario, higher capitalizataon-rate
requirements would, again, lower the
returns to stocks because of stock price
declines. Bond prices and returns
would suffer even more than stocks in
this scenario.
Disagreement with Jones's assump-
tions regarding the market reaction to
the deflation and inflation scenarios and
the subsequent impact on stocks would
lead to projected returns more attuned
to h~storical averages. His assumption
of a market correction appears reason-
able, however, in light of the long bull
market reflected in the returns to stocks
in the 1982-93 period and the market's
historically adverse reaction in short
periods to unexpected deflationary and
irdlat~onary environments as the market
seeks new equilibrium levels.
Assuming that the projected returns
in the different scenarios are reasonable,
Smith and Jones can calculate reason-
able returns for each of the four alterna-
tive portfolios in the three scenarios.
The portfolio returns are the weighted
averages of the projected asset-class re-
turns for each economic scenario. The
weightings would be the percentages
each asset class represents in the particu-
lar portfolio. The weighted real returns
of particular portfolios in the three eco-
nomic scenarios are given in Table A.
Cash was given no weighting in any of
75
Table A. Weighted-Average Real Returns of Selected Portfolios by Economic
Scenario
Asset M~x Degeanng Deflation tnt'tat;on
70% equity/30% debt 4.65% -4 35% -2 60%
60% equity/40% debt 4.45 -2.80 -2 $0
50% equity./50% debt 4.2.5 -1 25 -3 00
40% equity/60% debt 4.05 0.30 -3 20
the portfolios suggested for analysis and
is not included h~ any of the portfolio
descriptions.
The different portfolios exakibit sig-
rffficantly different return performance
in the three economic scenarios. In the
degearing scenario, an equity-heavy
portfolio performs slightly better than a
debt-heavy scenario, but in a deflatio/~
scenar2o, a debt-heavy portfolio per-
forms significantly better than an eq-
uity-heavy portfolio. Although none of
the portfolio mixes performs well in the
inflation scenario, an equity-heavy port-
folio does somewhat better than a debt-
heavy portfolio.
These return differences have sig-
nificant ~nplications for the asset-mix
recommendations Jones and Smith
should make to their boards. If, as Smith
apparently believes, a good possibility
exists that the degearing scenario could
deteriorate Lnto deflation, then the port-
folio should be debt heavy. TI-us strategy
would not significantly reduce returns
in the degearing scenario but would
provide significant protection against
the downside of deflation. In the i,rffla-
tion scenario, a shading toward equity
should produce the best (or least worst)
results. If the L~lation scenario is a vi-
able possibility, the only hedge available
would be a sizable allocation of the port-
folio to cash equivalents (T-bills).
Based on the three possible scenar-
ios, which of the four portfolio alterna-
fives evaluated in Table A should be rec-
ommended for the Alpha Corporation
fund and the PSRS fund?
Alpha Corporation's current asset
mix of 70 percent equity/30 percent debt
reflects the company's ability and will-
i~gness to assume larger risk than the
PSRS. If the asset-mix strategy does not
produce the desired real-return results,
Jones would have to inform the board of
directors that a larger future contribu-
tion to the corporation's pension plan is
required to provide its future defined
benefits. The result would be a reduc-
tion of corporate cash available for other
purposes for a trme. In conclusion,
given the possible capital market envi-
ronments for 1994 through 1998, and
given Jones's view that inflation is more
likely than deflation, Alpha Corporation
is likely to maintain its 70 percent eq-
uity/30 percent debt strategy.
The PSRS's current asset mix of 50
percent equity/50 percent debt reflects
its concerns about unfunded future li-
abilities and its resulting greater risk
aversion (relative to Alpha Corpora-
tion). If the PSRS's strategy does not
produce the desired real returns, the sys-
tem must request funds from the state
government, which revolves rinsing
taxes or cutting expenditures, and from
the employees, which mvolves addi-
tional contributions from their salaries.
Neither necessity would be painless.
Therefore, given the possible 1994--98
environments and given Smith's view
that deflation is more likely than L~a-
t-ion, the PSRS might find a 10-percent-
age-point sl'uft from equity to debt desir-
able. The resulting mi.x, 40 percent eq-
uity/60 percent debt, would be rela-
tively conservative. In addition, be-
cause of the i.rfflation sensitivity of the
plan's liabilities, the PSRS should con-
sider shortening the duration of the debt
portfolio.
76
et Allocation for Institutional
·
,1OS
San Francisco, California
~February 10-11, 1986
'Edited by
Michael D. Joehnk, CFA
P. Ambachtsheer
Robert D. Amott
Gary P. Brinson, CFA
Kathleen A. Condon, CFA
;H. Gifford Fong
William L. Fouse, CFA
Walter R. Good, CFA
Sponsored by
The Institute of Chartered
Financial Analysts
Mark P. Kritzman, CFA
Greta E. Marshall, CFA
Robert H. Litzenberger
Douglas A. Love
Roger F. Murray
Claude N. Rosenberg, Jr.
William F. Sharpe
Strategic Approaches to Asset Allocation
Keith P. Ambachtsheer
When considering the subject of "strategic ap-
proaches to asset allocation," one should first
ask what is meant by strategy, tactics, and the
many other descrzptors that are used in the area
of asset allocation. Why is asset allocation such
a foggy concept? Why are there such conceptual
difficulties in this area? It has a lot to do with
a confusion between means and ends. The defi-
nition I offer is: Asset allocation is the means
to achieve an appropriate package of risk, return,
and hme through the three steps of context un-
derstanding, future thinking, and decision im-
plementation.
ASSET ALLOCATION: THE LONG-
TERM CONTRACT
There are two basic contexts m which to study
asset allocation, and they should be kept sepa-
rate. Context number one is long-term asset allo-
cation. To illustrate long-term asset allocation,
consider the case of the hypothetical Alpha
Corporation. They have made that conceptual
breakthrough, and they think of their defined
benefits plan as a financial business. As such,
they recognize that understanding and manag-
ing the plan balance sheet is the appropriate
way to proceed.
As seen in Figure 1, Alpha Corporation is
a billion dollar company with a fairly normal
looking principal business balance sheet. But
Alpha uses the extended balance sheet concept,
and as shown on the pension plan balance sheet,
the assets and liabilities are very significant rela-
tive to the main business assets and liabilities.
Assets in the pension plan are stated at the mar-
ket, and liabilities are stated on a "best-estimate
going-concern basis." In other words, they use
economic assumptions on a best-estimate basis
about return and inflation. The going-concern
part means that it is important to recognize,
for the final earnings plans at least, that the
liability is based on final earnings, not on the
level or: earnings. Alpha Corporation has a signif-
icant asset cushion in the pension plan of $400
million, which in relation to the best estimate
of liabilities, amounts to a 44 percent asset cush-
ion.
When analyzing the pension plan balance
sheet, a number of policy issues need to be ad-
dressed. First is funding policy, or asset cushion
policy. Of concern here is the relationship be-
tween plan assets and projected plan liabilities
accrued to date. Should there be a large cushion
or a small cushion and why? The second issue
is asset mix policy, which deals with the left
side of the balance sheet. How are the assets
of the plan structured? Finally, there is a third
policy issue: investment management policy.
How will the asset mix policy be implemented?
Alpha's management realizes that there are
choices to be made. These can be seen in Figure
2, which shows the relationship between rates
of return of alternahve asset allocation policies.
The company can have anything from a return
maximization policy to a risk minimization pol-
icy. With the return maximization policy, the
asset mix required to achieve a long-term 5 per-
cent (or even higher) real rate of return is, of
course, a 100 percent equity policy. At the other
extreme, the risk minimizahon policy is a po[icy
FIGURE 1
Alpha Corporation (dollars m bdhons)
MAIN BUSINESS BALANCE SHEET
Assets Liabilities
Short term $1 2 Short term $0 6
Long term 1.2 Long term 0 8
$2.4 Sl.4
Equity
Shareholders equity.
Sl.0
Assets
Short term
Long term
PENSION PLAN BALANCE SHEET
Liabilities
$0 3 Short term $0 3
1 0 Long term 0 6
Sl .3 $0.9
Equity
Asset cushion $0 4
Source Ke~th P. Ambachtsheer & Assooates
24
FIGURE 2
Asset mix policy and long-term return targets
Realistic 6
real return
targets
(percent) 5
1
With For With
return broad r~sk
maximization market mlnlm~zahon
fOCuS portfoho fOCuS
Source Ke~th P Ambachtsheer & Asso~ates
of matching asset cash flows to liability cash
flows as closely as possible. The middle point
is to hold essentially the portfolio that the aggre-
gate of all investors hold, which should over
the long term achieve the same kind of real rate
of return as the real economy does in terms of
growth rate. That might be a 2.5 percent mid-
point.
The return projections are converted to im-
phc]t long-term contribution rates in Table 1.
Earlier it was pointed out that pension costs
are independent of the return on plan assets.
We can see that on a best-estimate basis, a 5
percent long-term real rate of return is consistent
with a long-term corporate contribution rate of
6 percent of the payroll (that is, a money transfer
from the principal business). That figure in-
cludes updating pension costs for 60 percent
of the CPI inflation rate. A striking range in
funding costs can occur depending on which
TABLE 1. Long-term economic assumptions
and normal plan costs
Long-term
Long-term normal cost
Asset class real return (percent of payroll)
Stocks 5% 6%
Real estate 4 7
Long bonds 2 10
T-bdls 5 14
Sourc~ Ke~lh P Ambachtsheer & Associates
asset mix is chosen, resulting in a potential long-
term contribution rate anywhere from 6 percent
to as high as 14 percent of payroll.
How does one choose? If this is the only
information, of course, the choice is obvious.
Go for the low contribution rate option. But this
decision is not that easy to make. The reason
is that sensible asset allocation decisions demand
a time context. For pension plans, the time frame
can be truly long term--probably in the neigh-
borhood of about 20 years But one cannot ignore
concerns about shorter-term contribution rate
variabxlity; for example, what might the contri-
bution rate have to be three to five years from
now? When you take a balance sheet perspec-
tive, the concern becomes the $400 million asset
cushion. Will it increase or decrease? Fluctua-
tions in this asset cushion could be quite signifi-
cant over a three- to five-year period.
So the fundamental issue in long-term asset
allocation is the question of trading off long-term
good news against the possibility of shorter-term
bad news. You can look at this dilemma in a
contribution rate context, where lower long-term
contributions must be balanced against greater
shorter-term contribution uncertainty. Alterna-
tively, you can look at it in a balance sheet context
and seek higher long-term asset cushion growth
against shorter-term cushion size uncertainty.
The good news is that the long-term contribution
rate, including updating pensions in pay for in-
flat]on, implies a 6 percent contribution rate.
FIGURE 3
The future contribution rate trade-off range
The Return Maximizing Pohcy The Risk Mm~m~zmg Pohcy
Good news Bad news
No good or baa news
Long-term
contributions
are
6%
of payroll
Shorter-term
contributions
could be over
15%
of payroll
in deflahon
S~urct Ke]th P. Arnbachtshe~r & Assooates
Contribubons
will not vary
far from
10%
ol payroll
~n short term
or long term
The bad news is that if you end up with an
extended period, perhaps three to five years,
when equities do very poorly, your contribution
rate could go up to 15 percent three to five years
later.
In the risk minimizing policy, there is no
good news or bad news by definition. Contribu-
t-ions will not vary far from 10 percent of payroll
in the short or long term (see Figure 3). Many
corporate managers, when they are shown these
alternatives, prefer to look at the trade-off in
the balance sheet context. The good news with
the return maximizmg policy is that continued
cushion growth means eventual lower corp6rate
contributions or higher benefits in the long term.
The bad news is that the cushion can disappear
in the shorter term. With the risk minimizing
pohcy, there is again no particularly good news
or bad news; cushion size is highly predictable
(see Figure 4).
THE ROLE OF FUTURE THINKING
IN ASSET ALLOCATION
Given the framework in which to make asset
allocation decisions, the next element in the deci-
sion process is dealing with an uncertain future.
In this context, dealing explicitly with uncer-
tainty is crucial. Over time, we have developed
two approaches to dealing with that future. The
first method, the Monte Carlo simulation, as-
sesses the future through a series of probabdity
distributions for stock returns, bond returns,
cash returns, and inflation returns and how they
are expected to be correlated. From those expec-
tations, a computer can develop hundreds or
FIGURE 4
The future asset cushion trade-off range
The Return Maximizing Policy The R~sR Minimizing Pohcy
Good news Bad news
No good or bad news
Continued
cusl3ion
growth
means lower
coats or
h~gher
benehts
in long term
Cushion
d~sappears
in
deflation
$~urce Ketth P Arabachtsheer & Associates.
Cushion
size
h~ghly
predictable
26
thousands of possible outcomes by drawing out
these distributions. The output, as illustrated
in Figure 5, shows contributions as a percent
of payroll on the left scale and different weight-
ings of equities as opposed to bonds across the
bottom. When moving from Iow risk to higher
risk, the percent of equities in the portfolio and
the potential contribution rate increases and the
50th percentile contribution rate decreases.
The other technique, called the scenario ap-
proach, is a little more hands-on and allows you
to put a little more color into the analysis. The
four possible scenarios are summarized in Table
2. To relate the scenario approach to dealing
with an uncertain future, again consider Alpha
Corporation. The implications for the Alpha
pension plan contribution rate depend on the
firm's asset allocation policy. For example, in
the deflation case, with the return maximizing
policy, the results are very unpleasant with the
projected contribution rate going way up (see
Figure 6). Figure 7 presents the same results
in a plan balance sheet (asset cushion) context.
DECISIONS AND
THEIR IMPLEMENTATION
After determining the context and allowing for
an uncertain future, the decision and implemen-
tation steps follow. In the case of Alpha Corpora-
t-ion, management decided that, as much as pos-
sible, they wanted to maximize long-term real
FIGURE $
D~stributions of contributions as a percent of payroll for various bond/stock asset mt,xes
Contribuhonslpayroll
(percent) (inverted scale)
10
6.3
7O
7.7
82
8.7
6.1
6.8
7.6
8.1
8.6
5.3
6.6
7.3
8.1
8.7
7.3
8.1
8.7
4,5
6O
72
8.2
8.8
4.1
56
7.1
8.3
9.1
I I t I I 1
A B C D E F
0% 20% 40% 50% 70% 90%
Percentile
90th
75th
50th
25th
10th
Percent in ecluihes
Source Bankers Trust Company
27
TABLE 2. Possible three- to five-year capital market environments
The environment
Good hmes' Steady output and productivity growth, Iow
inflation rate, post,ye expectations about the future.
Stagflat;on: Uneven output and productivity growth, infla-
tion rate in the 6-9 percent range, confused expectations
about the future
Pasmg inflation: Uneven output and productivity growth,
debt monet2zat~on, inflatuon rate nsmg above 10 percent,
dynamics expected to continue
Deflation: Output stagnant to falling, mflat~on low and fall-
ing, future looks bleak.
The capital markets
Stocks do very well, followed by real estate and long bonds
ShortIterrn investments left far behind
No pred:ctable differences in asset class returns
Real estate and other tangibles do best, stocks and short-
term investments mediocre, long bonds worse by far
High-quality long bonds best by far, cash mediocre, real
estate poor, stocks worst.
~ourct Ke:th P. Ambachtsheer & Assocuates
return, subject to "being whole" (that is, having
a positive asset cushion in the worst case out-
come) on a three- to five-year basis. Using this
particular set of numbers, being whole is
achieved through a significant real estate posi-
tion, which is the hedge against the rising infla-
tion outcome, and a sigmf~cant long-bond posi-
tion, which is the hedge against the deflation
outcome. The purpose for those two positions
is risk control. The "basic" asset mix in Fi_gu_re
8 results.
A lot of interesting things can be done with
the basic asset mix policy to improve its risk-
reward characteristics. See the expanded asset
mix policy in Figure 8. One aspect of the ex-
panded asset mix policy is the shift account.
That account can be in domestic stocks, long
bonds, or T-bills. It is funded from the basic
policy by taking 10 percentage points of the long-
bond position and 10 percentage points of the
stock position and putting them into a shift ac-
count. This is a good way to shift the focus
from an asset allocation approach that concen-
t-rates on risk control to one that concentrates
FIGURE 6
Sixth-year contribution rate prolecfions
Return
maxlmtzatlon
wdn "bad news"
Percent -15 --
-10
-5
0
5
10 --
15
20 -
$ourc~ Keah P Ambachtsheer & As$ocmte$.
Good times
Return Rtsk
maximization m~mm~zatlon
no "bad news"
Good times
Deflahon
Deflation [ [ R~sing
inflahon
Deflation
28
FIGURE 7
Five-year asset cushion swing projections
Return
maxtmizatmn
w~th "bad news"
$ billions 1,6 F
/
1.2
0,8
0.4
-0.4
Source Ke~th P Ambachtsheer & Assooates
Good times
Deflatfon
on value added. When moving to a short-term
asset allocation focus, however, the investment
context changes very significantly.
RISK CONTROL AND
RETURN ENHANCEMENT
Short-term asset allocation is a process that lo-
c :- ?s not on risk control but on return enhance-
-~ent. The objective is to add return to an other-
wise passive situahon. In the short-term asset
allocation context, we have to raise the question
as to whether there are correlations between
yesterday, today, and tomorrow. In other
words, are there relationships between past and
present observable events and future stock
prices and interest rates? How you answer that
question is absolutely crucial to whether you
should engage in short-term active asset alloca-
tion. If you believe there are no such linkages,
stop now. If you believe there are linkages that
can be identified, then there is a place for active
asset allocation.
Table 3 shows the five bases that have to
be touched to be effective, to maximize the
chances of success. Step I: What do you believe
about the relationships between events yester-
day and today and stock prices and interest rates
tomorrow? In other words, what is your theory
of capital assets pricing? You must consider that
Return R~sk
maximization mm~mlzahon
no "bad news"
Good times
Deflation
Deflation
= Rising
inflation
issue and think about your belief of how inflation
expectations will affect bond prices, the impact
of real GNP growth on stock prices, and so forth.
This leads to Step 2: Identify the predictors that
are important to security valuation. In effect,
what can I observe today that will affect the
valuation factors tomorrow? And you might say,
for example, "Well, I think monetary policy to-
day might affect inflation expectations tomor-
row,'' thereby identifying that particular pre-
dictor.
Step 3: What is the relationship between the
predictors and the variables that you are trying
to forecast (future stock prices and interest
rates)? In Step 3, you are actually thinking, for
example, about how sensitive changes in mone-
tary policy are today to changes in inflation ex-
pectations tomorrow--which, in turn, will im-
pact stock and bond prices tomorrow. Step 4:
Establish your decision rules. You can't just stop
with the output of the process in terms of expec-
tations about the future; you have to act on them
and you have to act on them in an intelligent
way. Decision rules used by money managers
are often quite naive. For example, managers
often do not consider that they might not be
perfect at making capital markets forecasts. Your
actual decision rules depend very much on how
good you thir~k your forecasts are and on the
transaction costs. These are the real world issues
29